Last week I was driving through Phoenix when I saw this sign at an intersection:
It struck me that this was a perfect example of what happens when clever business folks figure out a way to short circuit the normal laws of consumer behavior. How's it work? Bring your car in and the glass shop bills your insurance company directly and either rewards you with cash, or at least pays your deductible. Presumably folks who have insurance that will pay a lot get the $100 and folks with lower-end insurance only get $50... It's a perverse incentive which disrupts the usual laws of consumer economics.
Driving, I was immediately reminded of a similar situation in healthcare: pharmaceutical copay coupons. A couple of weeks ago HBS professor Leemore S. Dafny and colleagues published a compelling perspective piece in the New England Journal discussing the corrosive effect of "copayment coupons" offered by manufacturers directly to consumers.
Like the auto glass example , these pharmacy coupons given to patients and are used at the point of sale to offset the patient copays. For example, using a copay coupon, a patient can purchase a $1000 drug at less out-of-pocket cost (to him) than a comparable $20 generic which might have a $5 copay. The net effect: aggregate pharmacy costs past on the the insurer are far higher because there is no patient incentive to use less expensive but comparable generics.
My favorite example of this is the contemptible drug Nexium, which for all purposes interchangeable with the generic Prilosec (Omeprazole). (In fact, before it was non-generic, Prilosec was the "purple pill" <™ i'm sure> and Nexium inherited the title once omeprazole was generic at pennies a pill).
According to GoodRx, today 30 tablets of Nexium cost $300 cash price at most national pharmacies, whereas 30 tablets of generic Prilosec cost just $24. For the user using the Nexium Savings Card, Nexium costs $15 as compared to a generic co-pay that might be $20.
The problem with the coupons is that they dramatically undermine the insurance company's/ PBM's abilities to "tier" medication, which is the primary leverage they have over pharmaceutical manufacturers. Dafny writes:
According to the authors, over half of all non-generics now have coupons available. It's come at a terrible cost to the system:
At the end of the day, this Jiu-Jitsu at the point of sale
As an old colleague was fond of saying, and which I repeat often, healthcare is a balloon: squeeze one area and another bulges. This spigot of money flowing to the drug companies needs to be offset by reduced spending elsewhere, or by higher annual premiums. It's a perfect example of the tragedy of the commons, where individual users acting independently according to their own self-interest behave contrary to the common good of all users by depleting resources through their collective actions.
If you think that these increased premiums don't matter, consider Ms. Rosa Ines Rivera, a cafeteria worker at Harvard's School of Public Health who, with colleagues, is on strike, primarily to protest proposed increases in health insurance costs that Harvard wants to pass to employees. I was struck by an opinion piece she submitted to the New York Times yesterday:
It's the same conversation that many employers and employees are having, as they realize that drug company revenue "optimization" has come at a steep cost to the average American.
Comments